Open Access
How to translate text using browser tools
1 November 2013 The Rental Market for Farmland in Vietnam's Mountainous North Central Coast Region: Outcomes and Constraints
Van Le, Michael Lyne, Nazmun Ratna, Peter Nuthall
Author Affiliations +
Abstract

Vietnam's rural areas are characterized by small and fragmented farms, cost inefficiency, and low agricultural income. An efficient land rental market is expected to alleviate some of these problems by creating incentives for allocative efficiency. Voluntary rental transactions are also expected to improve the welfare of both lessees and lessors. This study investigates the efficiency and equity outcomes of the rental market for farmland in a commune in Vietnam's north central coast region, a mountainous area with relatively low incomes and a high concentration of ethnic minorities. It also examines the efficiency of the rental market itself, recognizing that market participation is affected by cultural norms and mutual trust. Data for the study were gathered in 2 household surveys, each conducted in 2 villages. The first was a multistage sample survey of 200 households; the second was a census survey of rental market participants. It was found that the rental market is encouraging households to trade their land use rights in mutually beneficial ways that transfer land to more effective farmers. But there is considerable room for improvement through increasing the number of market participants by reducing transaction costs associated with inadequate information, opportunism, and lack of confidence in the legal system. Perceived levels of risk differed between Kinh and Thai respondents.

Introduction

The Vietnamese government introduced market-based land reforms to promote the consolidation of farmland and growth of farms, starting with the 1993 Land Law (Vietnamese Government 1993). However, Vietnam's farms remain highly fragmented. For the whole country, there are about 75 million parcels of land, an average of 7 to 8 plots per farm household (Hung et al 2007). One explanation for this slow response is that the rural land market is inefficient (Ravallion and van de Walle 2003; CIEM 2005; Hung et al 2007; Deininger et al 2008). This study focuses on the rental market for farmland, because the current Land Law still imposes stringent limits on the area of land that households may own but allows farmers to lease additional land. Whereas voluntary rental transactions are expected to result in both efficiency and equity gains, sale transactions do not hold the same promise, especially when land is valued for purposes other than agriculture, such as social security (Deininger and Jin 2008).

The purpose of this study is to investigate the performance of the rental market for farmland in Tam Quang commune, which is located in a mountainous district in Vietnam's north central coast region. Consideration is given first to the efficiency and equity outcomes of the rental market, and then to the efficiency of the market itself. The study region is characterized by relatively low incomes and a high concentration of ethnic minorities (JICA 2008). Ethnic diversity is expected to increase transaction costs and so reduce market efficiency (Beghin and Fafchamps 1995). Ethnic groups differ in their cultural norms and levels of social capital, and these differences may also impact transaction costs and market efficiency within communities and locations (Charny 1990; Tsai 2000; Cersosimo and Nistico 2008).

This article is organized as follows: After a review of the literature on the expected benefits of an efficient rental market for farmland, developments in Vietnam's land rental market are outlined. Next, the study site and sampling method are described, and household demographics are compared across the 2 study villages. Observations on the performance of the land rental market and its equity and efficiency outcomes are then presented, followed by evidence of market inefficiency. The article concludes with recommendations for policy and future research.

Expected benefits of an efficient farmland rental market

Land markets comprise both rental and sale markets. Rental markets are widely recognized as having better allocative efficiency and equity outcomes than sale markets and often play a more important role than sale markets in developing countries and transitional economies characterized by tenure insecurity and market imperfection (Deininger and Jin 2008). From an efficiency perspective, the land rental market imposes an opportunity cost on underutilized and idle land. This promotes allocative efficiency, as owners of underutilized or idle land would rather rent out the land than forgo rental income. Consequently, transactions conducted in an efficient land rental market tend to transfer farmland from less effective to more effective farmers, that is, those more willing and able to farm (Crookes and Lyne 2003). Renting can also improve farming efficiency by allowing emerging farmers to consolidate land, thereby reducing losses associated with fragmentation (Hung et al 2007) and benefiting from economies of size in the adoption of new technology (Kille and Lyne 1993; Swinnen et al 2006). In addition, efficient land rental markets help overcome imperfections in markets for credit, insurance, and machinery through interlinked contracts such as crop-sharing arrangements (Otsuka et al 1992).

Voluntary transactions conducted in an efficient rental market are expected to benefit both lessor and lessee. Equity improves as land transfers to households that are short of land for subsistence or commercial farming purposes, while rental income accrues to those who cannot, or prefer not to, farm (Lyne 2009). Moreover, renting does not create a landless class, and where insurance and credit markets are imperfect or missing altogether, it can help farmers avoid permanent loss of land following adverse events such as crop failure.

An efficient land rental market is characterized by low transaction costs and security of land tenure (Nieuwoudt 1990). Transaction cost is defined as “the cost of obtaining information, establishing one's bargaining position, bargaining and arriving at a group decision, and enforcing the decision made” (Randall 1972: 176). Ex ante transaction costs relate to the process of conducting a transaction, including the costs of searching for trading partners and of negotiating and specifying the terms of the contracts. Ex post transaction costs include the costs of monitoring, renegotiating, and enforcing the terms of contract, and the risk of losses associated with a breach of contract. High transaction costs prevent markets from operating efficiently, and they are influenced by both legal infrastructure and social norms (Williamson 1979, 1985, 2000).

The quality of the legal infrastructure has important implications for transaction costs in the land rental market as it influences the enforceability of property rights (Place et al 1994). Lessors will perceive high risk in a rental transaction if they lack confidence in the legal system and its ability to defend their property rights against a claim made by tenants. This risk adds to the lessor's transaction costs and raises the offer price to prospective lessees, particularly those whose trustworthiness is unknown (Lyne and Thomson 1997). A similar problem exists on the lessee's side owing to the threat of eviction, that is, when they perceive that the duration of their contractual use right is not assured (Gordon 1890).

In addition to the quality of the legal system, social capital is considered to be an important factor affecting transaction costs and thus market efficiency (Williamson 1985, 2000; Charny 1990; Putnam 2000). Social capital refers to social networks that can facilitate productive actions between individuals (Coleman 1988; Putnam 2000; Narayan and Cassidy 2001; Adler 2002; Moran 2005). Trust, a central part of social capital, is expected to reduce transaction costs as it reduces the ex ante costs of finding suitable trading partners and the ex post costs associated with noncompliance (Charny 1990; Tsai 2000; Raiser 2008). However, different kinds of trust are expected to have different influences on transaction costs faced by individuals, and therefore different impacts on market efficiency (Putnam 2000).

Land reform in Vietnam

Under Vietnam's 1993 Land Law, land remained state property but individuals were assigned well-defined long-term rights to use, bequeath, transfer, and mortgage the land. The duration of these rights and ceilings imposed on the amount of land that could be held with these rights by individuals, households, and organizations were defined by the law and varied across different types of land—for example, agricultural, forest, residential, and industrial land (Vietnamese Government 1993). These institutional changes were considered necessary to promote land use efficiency through market-driven land redistribution and consolidation. In terms of redistribution, use rights were expected to transfer voluntarily from less effective to more effective farmers. In terms of consolidation, it was anticipated that farmers would exchange and merge highly fragmented parcels of land into larger, commercially viable farms (Marsh and MacAulay 2001; Do and Iyer 2007; World Bank 2010).

In 2003 the Vietnamese government issued Land Law No.13/2003/QH11 (Vietnamese Government 2003), replacing the 1993 Land Law. Although the new law extended the duration of land rights and relaxed the ceilings on the amount of land that could be held with these more secure rights, a farmer wishing to consolidate land in excess of the defined ceiling can do so only through temporary transfers of use rights. This law clearly emphasized the importance of the land rental market relative to the land sale market in Vietnam. The change in land policy reduced unused land from 13 million ha in 1993 to 3 million ha in 2008. While some of these gains have been attributed to the land market (World Bank 2010), several authors have argued that the market for farmland in Vietnam is still far from efficient and that a more efficient land market will help to raise stagnating levels of productivity in agriculture (Ravallion and van de Walle 2003; CIEM 2005; Marsh et al 2006; Hung et al 2007; Deininger et al 2008).

Given the significance of voluntary rental transactions to efforts to improve efficiency and equity outcomes, it is important to understand why the market is still inefficient in Vietnam. There is a dearth of research on the causes of inefficiency in Vietnam's land rental market. This study aimed to provide more information by investigating efficiency and equity outcomes of the market, levels of participation in the market, and factors affecting market participation, and to offer policy insights for promoting sustainable rural livelihoods.

Study site, data collection, and household demographics

The research was conducted in Tam Quang commune in the Tuong Duong district, a mountainous area in the north central coast region characterized by low incomes and a high incidence of Thai people, one of the largest ethnic minority groups in Vietnam. Tam Quang commune was chosen for study because of its diversity in land types, land uses, income sources, and cultures. This diversity is expected to create variation in household resource endowments and priorities, leading to differences in households' ability to use farmland profitably. Without these differences there would be no demand for voluntary land transactions.

Two household surveys, a sample survey and a census survey, were conducted in Tam Quang commune. The sample survey was designed to generate a representative sample of commune households. Two of the commune's villages (primary-stage units), Son Ha and Bai Xa, were selected with probability proportionate to an estimate of their size, where size was measured by the number of households. A random sample of farm households (secondary-stage units) was then drawn from a list of farm households constructed for each of the 2 sample villages. A constant sampling rate was applied to each sample village, and was sufficiently large to generate a total sample of 200 farm households. This self-weighting sampling process allowed sample statistics to be computed at the commune level without weights to account for differences in village size. Five of the 200 cases were excluded from the sample survey data set owing to incomplete questionnaires.

The census survey followed the sample survey and covered all rental market participants in each village. This survey provided information about lessees and lessors. Data were gathered early in 2012 by the first author and students from Vinh University using a structured questionnaire and personal interviews with household members. Although the data were analyzed quantitatively, many of the variables were qualitative, measuring respondents' perceptions on a Likert-type scale.

Despite the short distance (6 km) between Son Ha and Bai Xa, these villages have significant differences in socioeconomic and geographic features (Table 1). The vast majority of Son Ha's population is Thai; Bai Xa has a much larger share of Kinh people (the dominant ethnic group in Vietnam, accounting for more than 80% of the country's population). The proportion of household members classified as farmers is significantly lower in Bai Xa than in Son Ha. Conversely, Bai Xa households have a much higher proportion of members working in nonfarm enterprises and earn substantially higher off-farm incomes than do Son Ha households. Off-farm incomes are earned in seasonal farm labor and permanent jobs with local authorities and in factories. Although Son Ha households earn higher farm incomes, they are much poorer than their counterparts in Bai Xa. Bai Xa, which has a much lower proportion of Thai households, has a much higher proportion of adults with tertiary education.

TABLE 1

Characteristics of households in Son Ha and Bai Xa.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t01.tif

Despite their lower proportion of farmers, households in Bai Xa are endowed with much larger areas of lowland, which is flatter and better suited to arable farming than the highland. While mean household endowments of irrigated lowland are similar in both villages, households in Bai Xa average more than 10 times as much nonirrigated lowland than households in Son Ha (Table 2). The most important sources of farm income in both villages are maize and bamboo, which together account for more than 90% of household farm income.

TABLE 2

Land ownership in Son Ha and Bai Xa.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t02.tif

Equity and efficiency outcomes of the rental market

The census survey data (relating only to rental market participants) support the argument that rental transactions promote land use efficiency by transferring land to more effective farmers. The average value of farm equipment owned by lessees is 50 times higher than that of lessors (Table 3), indicating that land was transferred to households better equipped to farm it. In addition, lessee households have more than twice as many members available for farm labor. Lessees had also attended twice as many agricultural training courses over the previous 12 months. Differences in efficiency are perhaps best demonstrated by differences in income earned per unit of arable land; lessees earned almost 10 times as much per m2 as lessors from annual crops in the 2011/12 season. More than 90% of lessees claimed increases of 150–200% in yields on land that they leased (relative to yields previously achieved by their landlords). These improvements in yield can be attributed to better management and more intensive use of family labor rather than to heavier applications of purchased inputs. This may reflect liquidity constraints faced by lessees who earn relatively low off-farm incomes. Even so, lessees are clearly more willing and able to farm than are lessors.

TABLE 3

Efficiency and equity aspects of the land rental market.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t03.tif

Equity outcomes are often observed in the temporary transfer of land from land-rich to land-poor households, and in the transfer of rental income (or part of the crop) from income-rich tenants to cash-strapped landlords, particularly households headed by widowed women, who also tend to have less family labor (Bell 1990). The data presented in Table 3 provide some evidence of rental income transferring to female-headed households, which are more prevalent among lessors than among lessees. The average annual cash rental was US$ 25, and crop shares averaged one-third of the amount harvested. However, there is no evidence of land transferring from relatively land-rich lessors to more land-poor lessees. This may reflect the egalitarian way in which land was originally allocated to households when ownership was decollectivized (Tuong Duong 2010).

Table 4 reports the amounts of land operated by lessors and lessees. When compared with the land endowments presented in Table 3, it is evident that the rental market is creating an emerging class of larger, commercial farmers. Areas operated by lessees are much larger, for all classes of land, than the areas operated by lessors. Likewise, when compared with the commune means (computed from the sample survey data), the areas operated by lessees are markedly higher for the more productive lowland classes. It can therefore be argued that the consolidation of land by emerging commercial farmers is equity-enhancing as it closes the income gap between lessees and wealthier rural households that generally have higher off-farm incomes (Carlettor et al 2007).

TABLE 4

Amount of land cultivated by land type.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t04.tif

Efficiency of the rental market

Although the rental market is generating efficiency and equity gains, this does not mean that the market itself is efficient. The data presented in Table 5 suggest that the rental market could be performing much better. The incidence of market participation is one measure of rental market activity (Crookes and Lyne 2003). In the commune as a whole, more than half of willing lessees and lessors did not participate in the market. This suggests market inefficiency—particularly in Son Ha, which has much lower ratios of actual to willing lessees and lessors than does Bai Xa. Willing lessees and lessors are survey respondents who said that they wanted to participate in the market but did not do so. The vast majority of them (80%) attributed their nonparticipation to costs and risks associated with land rental transactions. The remaining 20%, all potential lessees, were constrained by cash flow problems.

TABLE 5

Rental market participation in Son Ha and Bai Xa.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t05.tif

It has been contended that transaction costs increase with increasing levels of ethnic diversity, possibly due to language and trust barriers across ethnic groups (Beghin and Fafchamps 1995). The data from this study lend some support to this argument, as 84% of the observed rental transactions were conducted between households that belonged to the same ethnic group. In Bai Xa, where the Kinh account for 37% of all households, only 15% of transactions involving Kinh participants also involved Thai participants.

Disaggregation of Kinh and Thai respondents (Table 6) shows that, for both groups, most observed rental transactions were conducted between friends and relatives. Crookes and Lyne (2001) interpret a high proportion of such personalized transactions as evidence of high risk perceptions in the presence of moral hazard (the possibility that a party to a transaction may not honor its terms) and absence of an effective legal system. When legal settlements are costly and time consuming and can harm future long-term cooperation, contracting between members of the same social network is expected to reduce ex post transaction costs, as the members are less likely to behave opportunistically due to moral sanctions (Charny 1990; Tsai 2000; Cersosimo and Nistico 2008).

TABLE 6

Perceived rental market transaction costs.a)

i0276-4741-33-4-416-t06.tif

Another reason for the high proportion of transactions between friends and relatives may simply be proximity; the costs of finding and farming a suitable plot are lower for land that is owned by neighbors, and neighbors tend to be friends or relatives. In this case, better access to information about willing participants and their land or land requirements may reduce ex ante transaction costs and promote market efficiency. Administrative fees attach only to contracts that are witnessed by a local government authority. These financial costs are trivial and unlikely to affect the selection of trading partners.

While both Kinh and Thai favored personalized rental transactions, levels of mutual trust appear to be higher in the Kinh group, as the ratio of actual to willing market participants was far greater for Kinh respondents (3.4) than for Thai respondents (0.8). This could point to different levels of trust, different social norms, or different levels of confidence in the legal system between the Kinh and Thai groups. The study used a 3-point Likert-type scale (where 1  =  low agreement and 3  =  high agreement) to explore perceptions of transaction costs related to moral hazard. The mean scores presented in Table 6 indicate that perceptions of moral hazard were not just higher among willing participants than among actual participants, but also that, among willing participants, they were higher for Thai respondents. A similar finding holds for perceptions of legal uncertainty, although the risk of rented land being expropriated by a local authority was not viewed as a significant threat by either Kinh or Thai respondents.

Conclusions

Survey results suggest that the land rental market is promoting both farming efficiency and equity in the study sites. The market is helping lessees who are more committed to increasing farming income and is thus reducing the income gap between lessees and lessors. At the same time, it gives households that do not have sufficient resources to farm their land effectively a chance to earn rental income by leasing out their land. However, these beneficial outcomes are constrained by market inefficiency, as expressed by the high proportion of households that do not participate in the market even though they would like to. Simple comparisons of group means suggest that participation in the rental market may be constrained by ex ante transaction costs caused by inadequate information and by ex post transaction costs associated with moral hazard and a lack of confidence in the legal system. These comparisons also suggest that levels of concern about opportunism and confidence in the legal system differ between ethnic groups. Future research should attempt to analyze the role of social capital and legal infrastructure relative to other determinants of market participation using a multivariate approach. The results are expected to inform recommendations aimed at bringing willing participants into the rental market to their mutual benefit and at improving land use efficiency.

Open access article: please credit the authors and the full source.

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Vietnamese government and from Lincoln University, New Zealand.

REFERENCES

1.

P Adler 2002. Social capital: Prospect for a new concept. Academy of Management Review 27(1):17–40. Google Scholar

2.

C Beghin M Fafchamps 1995. Constitutions, institutions and the political economy of farm policies: What empirical content? In: H Peter D Hedley editors. Agricultural competitiveness: Market forces and public choice. Proceedings of the Twenty-second International Conference of Agricultural Economists. Dartmouth, NH: Dartmouth Publishing Company. Google Scholar

3.

C Bell 1990. Reforming property rights in land and tenancy. World Bank Research Observer 5(2):143–166. Google Scholar

4.

G Carlettor K Covarrubias B Davis M Krausova K Stamoulis P Winter A Zezza 2007. Rural income generating activities in developing countries: Re-assessing the evidence. Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics 4(1):146–193. Google Scholar

5.

D Cersosimo R Nistico 2008. Social capital in economics. In: D Castiglione J Deth G Wolleb editors. The Handbook of Social Capital. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, pp 386–410. Google Scholar

6.

D Charny 1990. Nonlegal sanctions in commercial relationships. Harvard Law Review 104(373):375–466. Google Scholar

7.

CIEM [Central Institute of Economic Management]. 2005. The impact of land market processes on the poor “Implementing de Soto”: The case in North Vietnam. In: ADB [Asian Development Bank]. Mp4 Week 2005. Hanoi, Vietnam: ADB, pp 26–28.  http://www.markets4poor.org/m4p2/filedownload/M4P%20week%202005_eng.pdf; accessed on 19 September 2013. Google Scholar

8.

J Coleman 1988. Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology 94:95–120. Google Scholar

9.

T Crookes M Lyne 2003. Efficiency and equity gains in the rental market for arable land: Observations from a communal area of KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Development Southern Africa 20(5):577–591. Google Scholar

10.

K Deininger S Jin 2008. Land sales and rental markets in transition: Evidence from rural Vietnam. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 1(70):67–101. Google Scholar

11.

K Deininger S Jin H Nagarajan 2008. Efficiency and equity impacts of rural land rental restrictions: Evidence from India. European Economic Review 52:892–918. Google Scholar

12.

T Do L Iyer 2007. Land titling and rural transition in Vietnam. Economic Development and Cultural Change 56(3):531–579. Google Scholar

13.

C Gordon 1890. Land Tenure and Compensation for Unexhausted Improvements in Land. LSE Selected Pamphlets, LSE Library, London.  www.jstor.org/stable/60217355; accessed on 4 July 2011. Google Scholar

14.

P Hung T MacAulay S Marsh 2007. The economics of land fragmentation in the north of Vietnam. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 51:195–211. Google Scholar

15.

JICA [Japan International Cooperation Agency]. 2008. Master Plan Study on Improvement of Rural Living Conditions in Northwestern Mountainous Region in Viet Nam.  http://giamngheo.mpi.gov.vn/Portals/0/Filedinhkem/BaoCaoChuyenDe/master%20plan%20EN%201.pdf; accessed on 25 November 2011. Google Scholar

16.

G Kille M Lyne 1993. Investment on freehold and trust farms: Theory with some evidence from Kwazulu. Agrekon 32(3):101–109. Google Scholar

17.

M Lyne 2009. Institutional change to promote a rental market for cropland in the communal areas of KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. In: J Kirsten AR Dorward C Poulton N Vink editors. Institutional Economics Perspectives on African Agricultural Development. Washington, DC: IFPRI [International Food Policy Research Institute], pp 359–373. Google Scholar

18.

M Lyne D Thomson 1997. Creating opportunities for farmers in communal areas: Adapting institutions to promote an efficient rental market in arable land. In: J Kirsten J van Zyl N Vink editors. The Agricultural Democratisation of South Africa. Cape Town, South Africa: Francolin Publishers, pp 120–128. Google Scholar

19.

S Marsh P Hung N Dac T MacAulay 2006. Farm size change and the market for agricultural land rights in Vietnam since 1993. In: S Marsh T MacAulay P Hung editors. Agricultural Development and Land Policy in Vietnam. Monograph No. 123. Canberra, Australia: Australian Center for International Agricultural Research, pp 85–108. Google Scholar

20.

S Marsh T MacAulay 2001. Land reform and the development of commercial agriculture in Vietnam: Policy and issues. Paper presented at the Annual Conference of the Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society. Adelaide, South Australia, 23 January 2001. Google Scholar

21.

P Moran 2005. Structural vs. relational embeddedness: Social capital and managerial performance. Strategic Management Journal 26(12):1129–1151. Google Scholar

22.

D Narayan M Cassidy 2001. A dimensional approach to measuring social capital: Development and validation of a social capital inventory. Current Sociology 49(2):59–102. Google Scholar

23.

W Nieuwoudt 1990. Efficiency of land use. Agrekon 29:210–215. Google Scholar

24.

K Otsuka H Chuma Y Hayami 1992. Land and labor contracts in agrarian economies: Theories and facts. Journal of Economic Literature 30(4):1965–2018. Google Scholar

25.

F Place M Roth P Hazell 1994. Land tenure security and agricultural performance in Africa: Overview of research methodology. In: JW Bruce SE Migot-Adholla editors. Searching for Land Tenure Security in Africa. Dubuque, IA: Kendall/Hunt, pp 15–40. Google Scholar

26.

R Putnam 2000. Bowling Alone. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster. Google Scholar

27.

M Raiser 2008. Social capital and economic performance in transition economies. In: D Castiglione J Deth G Wolleb editors. The Handbook of Social Capital. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, pp 491–519. Google Scholar

28.

A Randall 1972. Market solutions to externality problems: Theory and practice. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 54(2):175–183. Google Scholar

29.

M Ravallion D van de Walle 2003. Land Allocation in Vietnam's Agrarian Transition. London, United Kingdom: Institute for Fiscal Studies.  www.ifs.org.uk/edepo/wps/ewp0303.pdf; accessed on 4 July 2012. Google Scholar

30.

J Swinnen L Vranken V Stanley 2006. Emerging Challenges of Land Rental Markets: A Review of Available Evidence for the Europe and Central Asia Region. Washington, DC: World Bank. Google Scholar

31.

W Tsai 2000. Social capital, strategic relatedness and the formation of intraorganizational linkages. Strategic Management Journal 21(9):925–939. Google Scholar

32.

Tuong Duong. 2010. Five-Year Socio-economic Report from 2005–2010. Tuong Duong District Authority, Nghe An Province, Vietnam. Google Scholar

33.

Vietnamese Government. 1993. Land Law 1993 No. 24L/CTN.  http://thuvienphapluat.vn/archive/Luat/Law-No-24-L-CTN-of-July-14-1993-on-Land-vb81475t10.aspx; accessed on 10 June 2011. Google Scholar

34.

Vietnamese Government. 2003. Land Law 2003 No. 13/2003/QH11.  www.vietnamlaws.com/freelaws/Lw13na26Nov03Land[X2865].pdf; accessed on 12 December 2012. Google Scholar

35.

O Williamson 1979. Transaction cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics 22(2):233–261. Google Scholar

36.

O Williamson 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York, NY: Free Press. Google Scholar

37.

O Williamson 2000. The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature 38(3):595–613. Google Scholar

38.

World Bank. 2010. Vietnam Development Report 2011: Natural Resources Management. Washington, DC: World Bank. Google Scholar
International Mountain Society
Van Le, Michael Lyne, Nazmun Ratna, and Peter Nuthall "The Rental Market for Farmland in Vietnam's Mountainous North Central Coast Region: Outcomes and Constraints," Mountain Research and Development 33(4), 416-423, (1 November 2013). https://doi.org/10.1659/MRD-JOURNAL-D-13-00009.1
Received: 1 July 2013; Accepted: 1 August 2013; Published: 1 November 2013
KEYWORDS
equity
land use efficiency
market efficiency
social capital
transaction costs
Vietnam
Back to Top